Cooperating with the future (original) (raw)
- Letter
- Published: 25 June 2014
Nature volume 511, pages 220–223 (2014)Cite this article
- 26k Accesses
- 248 Citations
- 481 Altmetric
- Metrics details
Subjects
Abstract
Overexploitation of renewable resources today has a high cost on the welfare of future generations1,2,3,4,5. Unlike in other public goods games6,7,8,9, however, future generations cannot reciprocate actions made today. What mechanisms can maintain cooperation with the future? To answer this question, we devise a new experimental paradigm, the ‘Intergenerational Goods Game’. A line-up of successive groups (generations) can each either extract a resource to exhaustion or leave something for the next group. Exhausting the resource maximizes the payoff for the present generation, but leaves all future generations empty-handed. Here we show that the resource is almost always destroyed if extraction decisions are made individually. This failure to cooperate with the future is driven primarily by a minority of individuals who extract far more than what is sustainable. In contrast, when extractions are democratically decided by vote, the resource is consistently sustained. Voting10,11,12,13,[14](/articles/nature13530#ref-CR14 "Kamei, K., Putterman, L. & Tyran, J.-R. State or nature? Formal vs. informal sanctioning in the voluntary provision of public goods. Exp. Econ. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-014-9405-0
(2014)"),[15](/articles/nature13530#ref-CR15 "Bernard, M., Dreber, A., Strimling, P. & Eriksson, K. The subgroup problem: When can binding voting on extractions from a common pool resource overcome the tragedy of the commons? J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 91, 122–130 (2013)") is effective for two reasons. First, it allows a majority of cooperators to restrain defectors. Second, it reassures conditional cooperators[16](/articles/nature13530#ref-CR16 "Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S. & Fehr, E. Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Econ. Lett. 71, 397–404 (2001)") that their efforts are not futile. Voting, however, only promotes sustainability if it is binding for all involved. Our results have implications for policy interventions designed to sustain intergenerational public goods.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution
Access options
Subscribe to this journal
Receive 51 print issues and online access
$199.00 per year
only $3.90 per issue
Buy this article
- Purchase on SpringerLink
- Instant access to full article PDF
Prices may be subject to local taxes which are calculated during checkout
Additional access options:
Similar content being viewed by others
References
- Hardin, G. The tragedy of the commons. Science 162, 1243–1248 (1968)
Article ADS CAS Google Scholar - Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions For Collective Action (Cambridge Univ. Press, 1990)
Book Google Scholar - Levin, S. A. Fragile Dominion: Complexity and the Commons (Basic Books, 2000)
Google Scholar - Milinski, M., Semmann, D., Krambeck, H. J. & Marotzke, J. Stabilizing the Earth’s climate is not a losing game: supporting evidence from public goods experiments. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 103, 3994–3998 (2006)
Article ADS CAS Google Scholar - Wade-Benzoni, K. A. & Tost, L. P. The egoism and altruism of intergenerational behavior. Pers. Soc. Psychol. Rev. 13, 165–193 (2009)
Article Google Scholar - Ostrom, E., Walker, J. & Gardner, R. Covenants with and without a sword: self-governance is possible. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 86, 404–417 (1992)
Article Google Scholar - Milinski, M., Semmann, D., Bakker, T. C. M. & Krambeck, H.-J. Cooperation through indirect reciprocity: image scoring or standing strategy? Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B 268, 2495–2501 (2001)
Article CAS Google Scholar - Fehr, E. & Gächter, S. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415, 137–140 (2002)
Article ADS CAS Google Scholar - Rand, D. G., Dreber, A., Ellingsen, T., Fudenberg, D. & Nowak, M. A. Positive interactions promote public cooperation. Science 325, 1272–1275 (2009)
Article ADS MathSciNet CAS Google Scholar - Holcombe, R. G. The median voter model in public choice theory. Public Choice 61, 115–125 (1989)
Article Google Scholar - Walker, J. M., Gardner, R., Herr, A. & Ostrom, E. Collective choice in the commons: experimental results on proposed allocation rules and votes. Econ. J. 110, 212–234 (2000)
Article Google Scholar - Ertan, A., Page, T. & Putterman, L. Who to punish? Individual decisions and majority rule in mitigating the free rider problem. Eur. Econ. Rev. 53, 495–511 (2009)
Article Google Scholar - Putterman, L., Tyran, J.-R. & Kamei, K. Public goods and voting on formal sanction schemes. J. Public Econ. 95, 1213–1222 (2011)
Article Google Scholar - Kamei, K., Putterman, L. & Tyran, J.-R. State or nature? Formal vs. informal sanctioning in the voluntary provision of public goods. Exp. Econ. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-014-9405-0 (2014)
- Bernard, M., Dreber, A., Strimling, P. & Eriksson, K. The subgroup problem: When can binding voting on extractions from a common pool resource overcome the tragedy of the commons? J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 91, 122–130 (2013)
Article Google Scholar - Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S. & Fehr, E. Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Econ. Lett. 71, 397–404 (2001)
Article Google Scholar - Coase, R. H. The problem of social cost. J. Law Econ. 3, 1–44 (1960)
Article Google Scholar - Mueller, D. C. Public Choice (Cambridge Univ. Press, 1979)
Google Scholar - Williamson, O. E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (Simon & Schuster, 1985)
Google Scholar - Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J. L., Savin, N. E. & Sefton, M. Fairness in simple bargaining games. Games Econ. Behav. 6, 347–369 (1994)
Article Google Scholar - Camerer, C. F. Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction (Princeton Univ. Press, 2003)
MATH Google Scholar - Charness, G. & Rabin, M. Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Q. J. Econ. 117, 817–869 (2002)
Article Google Scholar - Fosgaard, T., Hansen, L. G. & Wengström, E. Framing and misperceptions in a public good experiment. Working paper 2011/11. (Institute for Food and Resource Economics, 2011)
Google Scholar - Amir, O., Rand, D. G. & Gal, Y. K. Economic games on the internet: the effect of $1 stakes. PLoS ONE 7, e31461 (2012)
Article ADS CAS Google Scholar - Rand, D. G., Greene, J. D. & Nowak, M. A. Spontaneous giving and calculated greed. Nature 489, 427–430 (2012)
Article ADS CAS Google Scholar - Jacquet, J. et al. Intra-and intergenerational discounting in the climate game. Nature Climate Change 3, 1025–1028 (2013)
Article ADS Google Scholar - Cadsby, C. B. & Maynes, E. Gender and free riding in a threshold public goods game: experimental evidence. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 34, 603–620 (1998)
Article Google Scholar - Oullier, O. Behavioural insights are vital to policy-making. Nature 501, 463 (2013)
Article ADS CAS Google Scholar - Benkler, Y. The Penguin and the Leviathan: How Cooperation Triumphs Over Self-interest (Random House, 2011)
Google Scholar - Haynes, L., Service, O., Goldacre, B. & Torgerson, D. Test, learn, adapt: developing public policy with randomised controlled trials. UK Cabinet Office Behavioural Insights Team http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2131581 (2012)
Acknowledgements
We thank A. Dreber for discussion and three anonymous reviewers for helpful feedback. Financial support from the Department of Organismic and Evolutionary Biology at Harvard, the Harvard Office for Sustainability and the John Templeton Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
Author information
Author notes
- Oliver P. Hauser and David G. Rand: These authors contributed equally to this work.
Authors and Affiliations
- Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Harvard University, Cambridge, 02138, Massachusetts, USA
Oliver P. Hauser, Alexander Peysakhovich & Martin A. Nowak - Department of Organismic and Evolutionary Biology, Harvard University, Cambridge, 02138, Massachusetts, USA
Oliver P. Hauser & Martin A. Nowak - Department of Psychology, Yale University, New Haven, 06511, Connecticut, USA
David G. Rand & Alexander Peysakhovich - Department of Economics, Yale University, New Haven, 06511, Connecticut, USA
David G. Rand - Department of Mathematics, Harvard University, Cambridge, 02138, Massachusetts, USA
Martin A. Nowak
Authors
- Oliver P. Hauser
You can also search for this author inPubMed Google Scholar - David G. Rand
You can also search for this author inPubMed Google Scholar - Alexander Peysakhovich
You can also search for this author inPubMed Google Scholar - Martin A. Nowak
You can also search for this author inPubMed Google Scholar
Contributions
O.P.H., D.G.R., A.P. and M.A.N. designed and performed the experiments, analysed the data and wrote the paper.
Corresponding author
Correspondence toMartin A. Nowak.
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing financial interests.
Extended data figures and tables
Extended Data Figure 1 Bootstrapping simulations demonstrate the robustness of full voting and the failure of partial voting.
We address sources of noise in the sequence of events that occurred in our experiment by conducting a set of computer simulations using the data generated by our participants. We randomly sample (with replacement) a series of generations of participant decisions, and calculate the fraction of those generations in which the pool was refilled. For each condition, we simulate 10,000 pools (or 1,000,000 pools if δ < 0.8) for 15 generations. a, Simulated data for the unregulated, full voting and partial voting conditions show that full voting is by far the most successful at sustaining the pool. b, Simulated data for the T = 40%, T = 30%, δ = 0.7 and δ = 0.6 conditions shows that reducing δ has only a small effect, and although reducing T does undermine sustainability, the effect is much less striking than that of unregulated or partial voting despite the higher value of T in these less-regulated conditions.
Extended Data Figure 2 Countries with more democratic governments have more sustainable energy policies.
Energy sustainability index (as measured by the World Energy organization) is shown as a function of the democracy index (as measured by The Economist Intelligence Unit) for n = 128 countries. A strong positive association is clearly visible, and this association is robust to controlling for gross domestic product (GDP), Gini index, population size, literacy rate, unemployment rate, life expectancy and level of corruption. Thus we provide preliminary empirical support for the role of democracy in promoting sustainability outside the laboratory. We adopt the colouring and naming scheme from The Economist Intelligence Unit’s classification of regimes.
Supplementary information
Supplementary Information
This file contains Supplementary Text and Data, which includes Supplementary Methods, Supplementary Tables 1-7 and additional references. (PDF 2862 kb)
PowerPoint slides
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Hauser, O., Rand, D., Peysakhovich, A. et al. Cooperating with the future.Nature 511, 220–223 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1038/nature13530
- Received: 06 May 2013
- Accepted: 27 May 2014
- Published: 25 June 2014
- Issue Date: 10 July 2014
- DOI: https://doi.org/10.1038/nature13530
This article is cited by
Editorial Summary
A caring majority votes for the future
Cooperation is often seen in experimental economic games because actions can be reciprocated. But this trait is of no help in one of the most important types of cooperation: cooperation with future generations who cannot reciprocate if we refrain from overexploiting their resources. To test the conditions under which cooperation with the future can occur, Oliver Hauser et al. developed a laboratory model of cooperation — the Intergenerational Goods Game (IGG) — that differs from previous games in which selfishness creates social efficiency losses for group members. Instead, selfishness negatively impacts subsequent groups. Experiments involving more than 2,000 subjects demonstrate that when decisions on resource extraction are made individually, the resource is rapidly depleted by defectors. But when participants are forced to vote on how the resource should be exploited, it is exploited sustainably across generations. Voting works for two reasons. It allows a majority of cooperators to constrain a minority of defectors, and as all players receive the same amount after a vote, cooperators need not worry about losing out relative to others.