Does WTO Dispute Settlement Enforce or Inform? | British Journal of Political Science | Cambridge Core (original) (raw)

Abstract

Whereas some researchers emphasize how World Trade Organization (WTO) dispute settlement reduces complexity and clarifies legislation, others argue that dispute rulings promote co-operation by providing an enforcement mechanism. This article identifies empirical implications from these distinct arguments and tests them on WTO disputes from 1995 to 2006. The study's analytical approach combines a three-step coding of dispute escalation with a strategic bargaining model and statistical backwards induction to account for governments’ forward-looking behavior. It finds strong support for the argument that WTO dispute settlement primarily serves as an enforcement device. It finds much less support for the argument that dispute settlement reduces complexity and clarifies trade law. These results suggest that the role of WTO dispute settlement in generating information on acceptable trade policy standards is less relevant than proponents of the complexity argument tend to assume.

References

Abbott, Kenneth W. Snidal, Duncan. 1998. Why States Act Through Formal International Organizations. The Journal of Conflict Resolution 42:3–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Allee, Todd. 2010a. The Distinctiveness of Developing Country Trade Dispute Initiation. Manuscript, University of Illinois.Google Scholar

Allee, Todd. 2010b. Legal Incentives and Domestic Rewards: A Litigation Model of GATT/WTO Dispute Resolution. Manuscript, University of Illinois.Google Scholar

Allee, Todd Huth, Paul. 2006. Legitimizing Dispute Settlement: International Legal Rulings as Domestic Political Cover. American Political Science Review 100:219–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Barrett, Scott. 2006. Environment and Statecraft: The Strategy of Environmental Treaty-Making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar

Bas, Muhammet A., Signorino, Curis S. Walker, Robert W.. 2008. Statistical Backwards Induction: A Simple Method for Estimating Recursive Strategic Models. Political Analysis 16:21–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Bechtel, Michael, Sattler., Thomas Forthcoming. What is Litigation in the WTO Worth? International Organization. Google Scholar

Bernauer, Thomas. 2003. Genes, Trade and Regulation: The Seeds of Conflict in Food Biotechnology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar

Bernauer, Thomas, Elsig, Manfred Pauwelyn, Joost. 2012. The Dispute Settlement Mechanism: Analysis and Problems. In The Oxford Handbook on the World Trade Organization, edited by Amrita Narlikar, Martin Daunton, and Robert M. Stern, 485–506. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar

Bernauer, Thomas Meins, Erika. 2003. Technological Revolution Meets Policy and the Market: Explaining Cross-National Differences in Agricultural Biotechnology Regulation. European Journal of Political Research 42:643–683.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Bown, Chad P. 2004a. Developing Countries as Plaintiffs and Defendants in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes. The World Economy 27:59–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Bown, Chad P. 2004b. On the Economic Success of GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement. Review of Economics and Statistics 86:811–823.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Busch, Marc L. Reinhardt, Eric. 2000. Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: Early Settlement in GATT/WTO Disputes. Fordham International Law Journal 24:158–172.Google Scholar

Chayes, Abram Chayes, Antonia H.. 1993. On Compliance. International Organization 47:175–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Davis, Christina L. 2008. The Effectiveness of WTO Dispute Settlement: An Evaluation of Negotiation Versus Adjudication Strategies. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, MA 28–31 August.Google Scholar

Davis, Christina L. Bermeo, Sarah B.. 2009. Who Files? Developing Country Participation in GATT/WTO Adjudication. Journal of Politics 71:1033–1049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Davis, Christina L. Shirato, Yuki. 2007. Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan's Selection of WTO Disputes. World Politics 59:274–313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Downs, George, Rocke, David M. Barsoom, Peter. 1996. Is the Good News About Compliance Good News for Cooperation? International Organization 53:379–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Elsig, Manfred Stucki, Philipp. 2012. Low-Income Developing Countries and WTO Litigation: Why Wake Up the Sleeping Dog? Review of International Political Economy 19:292–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Fearon, James D. 1994. Signaling Versus the Balance of Power and Interests: An Empirical Test of a Crisis Bargaining Model. Journal of Conflict Resolution 38:236–269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Fearon, James D. 1995. Rationalist Explanations for War. International Organization 49:379–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Francois, Joseph, Horn, Henrik, Kaunitz., Niklas 2008. Trading Profiles and Developing Country Participation in the WTO Dispute Settlement System. International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development Issue Paper No. 6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Goldstein, Judith O., Kahler, Miles, Keohane, Robert O. Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 2000. Introduction: Legalization and World Politics. International Organization 54:385–399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Guzman, Andrew. 2002. The Cost of Credibility: Explaining Resistance to Interstate Dispute Resolution Mechanisms. Journal of Legal Studies 31:303–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Guzman, Andrew Simmons, Beth A.. 2002. To Settle or Empanel? An Empirical Analysis of Litigation and Settlement at the World Trade Organisation. Journal of Legal Studies 31:205–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Hofmann, Tobias, Kim., Soo Yeon 2009. The Political Economy of Compliance in WTO Disputes. Paper Presented at the International Political Economy Society Conference, College Station, TX, 13–14 November.Google Scholar

Hudec, Robert E. 1993. Enforcing International Trade Law: The Evolution of the Modern GATT Legal System. Salem, NH: Butterworth Legal Publishers.Google Scholar

Jervis, Robert. 1976. Perception and Misperception in International Relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar

Keohane, Robert. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation, and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar

Koremenos, Barbara, Lipson, Charles Snidal, Duncan. 2001. The Rational Design of International Institutions. International Organization 55:761–799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Lewis, Jeffrey B. Schultz, Kenneth A.. 2003. Revealing Preferences: Empirical Estimation of a Crisis Bargaining Game with Incomplete Information. Political Analysis 11:345–367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Milgrom, Paul Roberts, John. 1992. Economics, Organization, and Management. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar

Mitchell, Ronald B. 2006. Problem Structure, Institutional Design, and the Relative Effectiveness of International Environmental Agreements. Global Environmental Politics 6:72–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Moravcsik, Andrew. 2000. The Origins of Human Rights Regimes: Democratic Delegation in Postwar Europe. International Organization 54:217–252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Olson, Mancur. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar

Posner, Eric A. Yoo, John C.. 2005. Judicial Independence in International Tribunals. California Law Review 93:3–74.Google Scholar

Reinhardt, Eric. 2001. Adjudication Without Enforcement in GATT Disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution 452:174–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Rosendorff, B. Peter. 2005. Stability and Rigidity: Politics and Design of WTO's Dispute Settlement Procedure. American Political Science Review 99:389–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Rosendorff, B. Peter Milner, Helen. 2001. The Optimal Design of International Trade Institutions: Uncertainty and Escape. International Organization 55:829–857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Sattler, Thomas Bernauer, Thomas. 2011. Gravitation or Discrimination? Determinants of Litigation in the World Trade Organization. European Journal of Political Research 50 (2):143–167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Signorino, Curis S. 1999. Strategic Interaction and the Statistical Analysis of International Conflict. American Political Science Review 93:279–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Signorino, Curis S. Tarar, Ahmer. 2006. A Unified Theory and Test of Extended Immediate Deterrence. American Journal of Political Science 50:586–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Simmons, Beth A. 2000. International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs. American Political Science Review 94:819–835.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Smith, James M. 2000. The Politics of Dispute Settlement Design: Explaining Legalism in Regional Trade Pacts. International Organization 54 (1):137–180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Stone, Randall W., Slantchev, Branislav L. London, Tamar R.. 2008. Choosing How to Cooperate: A Repeated Public-goods Model of International Relations. International Studies Quarterly 52 (2):335–362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Stone Sweet, Alec Brunell, Thomas. 1998. Constructing a Supranational Constitution: Dispute Resolution and Governance in the European Community. American Political Science Review 92:63–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Underdal, Arild. 1998. Explaining Compliance and Defection: Three Models. European Journal of International Relations 4:5–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Whang, Taehee. 2010. Empirical Implications of Signaling Models: Estimation of Belief Updating in International Crisis Bargaining. Political Analysis 18:381–402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Williamson, Oliver. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar

Young, Oran R. 1994. International Governance: Protecting the Environment in a Stateless Society. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar