Capitalism Exterminism Moral Economy (original) (raw)

"E.P. Thompson and Moral Economies," A Companion to Moral Anthropology, Didier Fassin, ed. 2012

Britirh cultural histor;an Edward Palmcr Thompson ( 1924 93) ,Iisht well hive bccn a revercd ancestor fbr today's anthropologisrs, but instead he is Jikc a specter whosc traccs ir€ ub;quitous but who remains aLnost invisible. Thompson was a socisl constructiorlist bcfore social constructionism, a fervent antistructuralist bclbre fte poststmctunlist turn, 3n carly ProponeDt ofthc ;mportance of"agen y" and "exPeri irce" in social analysir, ud a tcn.rdous polcmicist :uld milihnt intclcctual before anthropology embraced activism. Yet whilc Thompsot]'s ideas pcrvrdc contemPor'ry

The Moral Economists: R. H. Tawney, Karl Polanyi, E. P. Thompson, and the Critique of Capitalism (review)

A review of: The Moral Economists: R. H. Tawney, Karl Polanyi, E. P. Thompson, and the Critique of Capitalism, by Tim Rogan, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press, 2017, 280 pp., $39.95/£32.95 (cloth)

Moral Economies Revisited

Annales Histoire Sciences Sociales, 2009

Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton; École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris 1 "There are no simple concepts. Every concept has components and is defined by them. [.. .] Obviously, every concept has a history [.. .] even though this history zigzags and passes, if need be, through other problems or onto different planes. [.. .] But a concept also has a becoming that involves its relationship with concepts situated on the same plane. Here, concepts link up with each other, support one another, coordinate their contours, articulate their respective problems, and belong to the same philosophy, even if they have different histories." [2] [2] Gilles Deleuze and Félix Guattari, What is Philosophy?... In reconsidering the famous concept he had forged two decades earlier and responding to his colleagues' critiques, Edward Palmer Thompson made this unexpected concession in a 1991 paper: Maybe the trouble lies with the word 'moral.' 'Moral' is a signal which brings on a rush of polemical blood to the academic head. Nothing has made my critics angrier than the notion that a food rioter might have been more 'moral' than a disciple of Adam Smith. But that was not my meaning [.. .]. I could perhaps have called this 'a sociological economy,' and an economy in its original meaning (oeconomy) as the due organization of a household, in which each part is related to the whole and each member acknowledges his various duties and obligations. That is just as 'political'-or more-'political'-than 'political economy.' However, classical economists have appropriated the term. [3] [3] Edward P. Thompson, Customs in Common (London: The... Thus, even though the originality of his concept lay in introducing a moral dimension to a Marxist reading of the economic and social history of the working class, twenty years later, Thompson seemed to be no longer making that claim, preferring instead the unlikely term "sociological" or the classic adjective "political." However, this admission is less surprising than one might think. In reality, not only had the success of the phrase not been anticipated by the British historian, but the concept itself had been introduced surreptitiously, almost without conviction. In The Making of the English Working Class, [4] published in 1963, the term "moral economy" appears incidentally when referring to the looting of stores and warehouses in times of rising bread prices: "It was legitimized by assumptions of an older moral economy, which taught the immorality of any unfair method of forcing up the price of [4] Edward P. Thompson, The Making of the English Working...

Chapter 1 of 'The Ethics of Capitalism'

Oxford University Press, 2020

(NOTE: uncorrected proof version) This chapter presents the basic question of this textbook: what might be meant by asking about the “ethics” of capitalism? And what makes this question so important that it gets its own book? The chapter then proceeds by first clarifying the intellectual discipline of political economy, emphasizing its philosophical and moralized content. This helps draw attention to the problem of economic justice. The chapter then distinguishes capitalism from alternative institutional systems before articulating the key questions about capitalism and justice that will be discussed in the larger body of the book, as well as the methods used to consider various answers to such questions.

Political Economy and the Historians.(3)

2019

E. P. Thompson had more in common with the political economy he criticised than he realised. Just as he placed his own radicalism in opposition to a thoroughly statized and oppressive form of socialism so also political economy set itself against the tyranny of the old aristocratic order. In looking for an alternative to the objective Marxism that went along with statized socialism, Thompson uncovered the history of an active subject, a class that made itself. Similarly, political economy had looked to an order founded on self-direction as the viable alternative to the hand of the aristocrats. In both cases then the basis for an alternative to a form of centralized political control was looked for in a formaterte