Do Security Measures Displace Crime? Theory and Evidence from Italian Bank Robberies* (original) (raw)

The Race Between Deterrence and Displacement: Theory and Evidence from Bank Robberies

The Review of Economics and Statistics

Security measures that deter crime may unwittingly displace it to neighboring areas, but evidence of displacement is scarce. We exploit precise information on the timing and locations of all Italian bank robberies and security guard hirings/firings over a decade to estimate deterrence and displacement effects of guards. A guard lowers the likelihood a bank is robbed by 35-40%. Over half of this reduction is displaced to nearby unguarded banks. Theory suggests optimal policy to mitigate this spillover is ambiguous. Our findings indicate restricting guards in sparse, rural markets and requiring guards in dense, urban markets could be socially beneficial.

The economic consequences of crime in Italy Article information

If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.

The crime drop and the security hypothesis

Major crime drops were experienced in the United States and most other industrialized countries for a decade from the early to mid-1990s. Yet there is little agreement over explanation or lessons for policy. Here it is proposed that change in the quantity and quality of security was a key driver of the crime drop. From evidence relating to vehicle theft in two countries, it is concluded that electronic immobilizers and central locking were particularly effective. It is suggested that reduced car theft may have induced drops in other crime including violence. From this platform, a broader security hypothesis, linked to routine activity and opportunity theory, is outlined.

Estimating a crime equation in the presence of organized crime: evidence from Italy

International Review of Law and Economics, 1997

We estimate a crime equation using a panel dataset of Italian regions for the period 1980 to 1989. Four different crimes are considered: murder, theft, robbery, and fraud. To take account of the presence of criminal organizations--a salient feature of the Italian context and a relevant factor usually disregarded by the empirical literature--we exploit the panel structure with unobservable individual components. Our results suggest that: (i) the probability of punishment is relatively more effective than both the severity of punishment and the efficiency of police authority in deterring crime; (ii) among the variables representing the opportunity costs of participating in illegal activities, the rate of unemployment, the value of public works started by government, and the proportion of people employed in the service sector have a significant effect; (iii) for three types of crime the regional unobservable component is correlated with the regressors; (iv) spillovers from drug consumption to theft are substantial; and (v) with the exception of fraud, the results are in contrast with the predictions of the standard economic model of crime. © 1997 by Elsevier Science Inc.

Counting the cost of crime in Italy

Global Crime, 2010

The aim of this paper is to gauge the cost of crime in Italy by concentrating on a subset of offences covering about 64% of total recorded crime in year 2006. Following the breakdown of costs put forward by Brand and Price, we focus on the costs in anticipation, as a consequence and in response to a specific offence. The estimated total social cost is more than € 38 billion, which amounts to about 2.6% of Italy's GDP. To show the usefulness of these measures, we borrow the elasticity estimates from recent studies concerning the determinants of crime in Italy and calculate the cost associated with the surge in crime fuelled by unemployment and pardons. Indeed, in both cases such costs are substantial, implying that they should no longer be skipped when assessing the relative desirability of public policies towards crime.

The economics of private security expenditure: The influence of perceptions of crime

Security Journal, 2017

Given that crime is a complex societal problem, the argument to embrace interdisciplinary scholarship seems an obvious one. The study of crime and its control, however, has largely remained multidisciplinary in nature. In this article, we provide an interdisciplinary, accessible economic model for understanding choices by individuals, as well as demonstrate the application of self-reported life satisfaction data to the issue of property crime. We find that: individuals' perceptions of crime in their local area are far greater than actual levels of crime; the gap between perceived and real crime is widening; and real crime rates detract more from an individual's self-reported life satisfaction than perceived rates of crime. However, perceived rates of crime have an adverse impact on life satisfaction beyond those associated with real crime. Together, these results suggest that societal welfare could be significantly enhanced by reducing individual's perceptions of crime, irrespective of any changes in the real crime rate.

Private security: Deterrent or diversion?

International Review of Law and Economics, 1994

Window bars, chain-link fences, and guard dogs are ubiquitous in wealthy Asian homes from New Delhi to Taipei. By contrast, all of these are rare in similar British, Canadian, and U.S. residential districts without the rate of property crime being substantially higher.' Generally, private security expenditures have two effects (Clotfelter, 1978; Clarke, 1983; Cook , 1986; and Shavell, 1991). First, they may deter some potential criminals, i.e., persuade them not to attempt crime at all. Second, they may also divert criminals towards other potential victims. 2 To the extent that security expenditures divert crime, their marginal effect on crime will be lower, which would be consistent with the contrast between Asia and the West noted above. Empirical evidence (from Britain) on the diversionary effect, however, is mixed. The installation of additional surveillance cameras in selected London Underground stations appeared not to divert crime to other stations (Mayhew, Clarke, et al., 1979). By contrast, after steering column locks were required on new cars, theft of new cars fell, while theft of older cars rose (Mayhew, Clarke, et al., 1976). Can these two apparently conflicting observations be reconciled? We thank Steve Shave11 for generous advice and encouragement on this paper 'With regard to institutional expenditures, Cunningham and Taylor (1984) estimated that in 1980 U.S. institutions spent a total of 2I.7billiononprivateprotectivegoodsandservices,comparedwithatotallossof2 I .7 billion on private protective goods and services, compared with a total loss of 2I.7billiononprivateprotectivegoodsandservices,comparedwithatotallossoft?7 billion from economic crime in the same year. Using different methods, Laband and Sophocleus (1992) give a substantially higher estimate of $157.83 b.ll' I mn for security expenditures in 1985. Tullock (1967) was one of the first scholars to emphasize private security expenditures as an important consequence of crime. 'Strictly, only security expenditures that potential criminals can observe have both effects. By contrast, precautions that cannot be identified with a particular victim have only the deterrent effect (Friedman, 1984; Shavell, 1991). For instance, in British public housing, a major burglary target is coin-fed electricity and gas meters. When these were replaced by conventional billing in some houses, the burglary rate for all units in the estate fell. Potential burglars could not tell from outside whether a particular house had a coin meter or conventional billing (Pease, 1992).

The Spatial Economic Impact of Crime: Evidence from the Construction Sector in Italian Municipalities

CESifo Economic Studies

Literature has mainly focused on understanding whether organized crime impacts on economic growth, broadly intended. Yet, at the local level, little is known as to how crime may affect economic activities. Using a unique geo-localized dataset on Italian firms, we exploit the strengthening of policy enforcement against corruption to show that when municipalities where the city council is dissolved because of organized-crime infiltration, the construction sector suffers a 7% reduction in the value added of firms located in the same area where the council dissolution occurred. We also find that the effect is larger, the longer the commissioner is present in the municipal council. Taken together our findings suggest that the action of the commissioner depresses the economic activity in the construction sector of the area where the temporary-administered municipality is located, given that it blocks all those relationships with firms related with criminality. This calls for a contemporan...

Crime and the (Mediterranean) city : exploring the geography of (in) security in Rome, Italy

2012

The spatial distribution of a selection of crime and demographic indicators in urban and suburban Rome, Italy, was explored in this paper to correlate socioeconomic conditions with urban deviance at local scale. An index of crime concentration was derived at district scale by composing all crime indicators. A principal components analysis was undertaken to correlate crime indicators with the socioeconomic context described through economic and demographic variables, living conditions, and the environmental quality. The geographical distribution of crime in Rome showed a pattern mainly associated to variables including population density, settlement form (compact vs dispersed), income, and unemployment. The spatial distribution of some crime indicators was finally compared with the citizens’ perception of security as it was measured by a specific field survey carried out at the same spatial scale. The paper illustrates that the integration between statistical data and qualitative inf...

Property Crime and Law Enforcement in Italy. A Regional Panel Analysis 1980-95

2003

In this paper a Cobb-Douglas utility function is introduced and solved for a dynamic equation of property crime supply and its determinants, namely deterrents and income. Thereafter, all variables are empirically tested by means of a simultaneous equations model, for the sign and magnitude of their mutual relationships in a panel of Italy and its two economically and culturally different areas, the North and the South.