Europe's long-term climate target: A critical evaluation (original) (raw)
Abstract
The European Commission as a whole and a number of its Member States individually have adopted a stringent long-term target for climate policy, namely that the global mean temperature should not rise more than 2
°C above pre-industrial times. This target is supported by rather thin arguments, based on inadequate methods, sloppy reasoning, and selective citation from a very narrow set of studies. In the scientific literature on “dangerous interference with the climate system”, most studies discuss either methodological issues, or carefully lay out the arguments for or against a particular target. These studies do not make specific recommendations, with the exception of cost-benefit analyses, which unanimously argue for less stringent policy targets. However, there are also a few “scientific” studies that recommend a target without supporting argumentation. Overall, the 2
°C target of the EU seems unfounded.
Introduction
The European Union as a whole and some of its Member States individually have proposed a long-term target for international climate policy, which is that the world should not warm more than 2
°C above pre-industrial temperatures.1 This is an ambitious target. Given the current uncertainties, it would imply that the atmospheric concentration of carbon dioxide could not rise much above 400
ppm (Meinshausen, 2005), only some 20
ppm above today's concentration; if recent trends continue, the 400
ppm level would be reached by 2020 (after Keeling and Whorf, 2005). This paper reviews the reasons for adopting this target.
Previously, another target was circulated, namely that the rate of warming should not exceed 0.1
°C per decade. Although this target was frequently mentioned (e.g., Swart et al., 1989; Swart and Hootsmans, 1991), the main defence was always a reference to a previous paper. The 0.1
°C/decade target can be traced to the late 1980s, but then the trace vanishes. Apocryphal evidence2 holds that the 0.1
°C/decade target is appropriate for a plant species on the shores of a lake in North America. This study was never published, but mentioned at dinner during an early climate conference. Someone else repeated the information the next day in plenary, and an urban legend was born. As the 0.1
°C/decade target has vanished from policy discussions—perhaps because natural variability is greater3—it need not concern us any further. However, it is important to know whether the 2
°C is valid or similarly based on bogus science.
The 2
°C target is already almost 10 years old.4 It was first raised in WBGU (1995), and adopted in CEU—Council of the European Union (1996). It was little prominent for a while, but recently it has surfaced again (e.g., CEU—Council of the European Union, 2004) as the preparations for climate policy in the period after 2012 (the end of the first commitment period under the Kyoto Protocol) are starting. As the EU is one of the main players in international climate policy, its long-term target requires serious discussion.
The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 reviews the official documents that present the 2
°C target. The focus is on the European Union, Germany, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. These three countries are at the forefront of European climate policy, and the author happens to be able to read their languages. Section 3 reviews the scientific literature that may substantiate, perhaps even justify a 2
°C target. Section 4 concludes.
This paper focuses on a particular target. Oppenheimer and Petsonk (2005) study the origin and varying interpretations of long-term targets for climate policy. Note that this paper does not suggest an alternative target for international climate policy. Although it does criticize the choice of target by the European Union, the main criticism is directed at the procedure by which this standard was set.
Section snippets
A review of official documents
CEC (2005a) repeats the earlier EU position that it “believes that global average temperatures should not exceed 2
°C above pre-industrial level”. The aim of CEC (2005a) is to conduct “a cost benefit analysis which takes account both of environmental and competitiveness considerations” [emphasis added].5
A review of the scientific literature
Campbell-Lendrum et al. (2003) is often quoted on the impacts of climate change on human health. This study does not recommend any temperature target. Instead, it compares impacts for unmitigated climate change, stabilisation at 750 and 550
ppm. Unfortunately, it does this comparison at 2030 only, at which time the three scenarios are hardly distinguishable. The stabilisation scenarios are the so-called “S” scenarios, which are unnecessarily expensive (Wigley et al., 1996), but Campbell-Lendrum
Discussion and conclusion
I reviewed Europe's 2
°C target for international climate policy in the long run. One may of course dismiss this target. Why does Europe decide on a global target? Are the days of colonialism not long past? It is of course perfectly legitimate for the EU to propose a global target. One may also dismiss Europe's target as just another grand plan, bound to suffer the same fate as the Stability and Growth Pact and the Lisbon Agenda, to name two recent grand plans by European governments that were
Acknowledgements
Sari Kovats and an anonymous referee provided helpful comments. The Michael Otto Foundation for Environmental Protection, the Hamburg University Innovation Fund and the Princeton Environmental Institute financially supported this research. All errors and opinions are mine.
References (79)
Global Environmental Change
(2004)
- D.J. Maddison
A cost-benefit analysis of slowing climate change
Energy Policy
(1995)
- A.S. Manne et al.
MERGE—a model for evaluating regional and global effects of GHG reduction policies
Energy Policy
(1995)
- W.J.M. Martens et al.
Climate change and vector-borne diseases—a global modelling perspective
Global Environmental Change
(1995)
- R.J. Nicholls et al.
Benefits of mitigation of climate change for coastal areas
Global Environmental Change
(2004)
- M. Parry et al.
Millions at risk: defining critical climate change threats and targets
Global Environmental Change
(2001)
- M.L. Parry et al.
What is Dangerous Climate Change?
Global Environmental Change
(1996)
- R.S.J. Tol
The marginal damage costs of carbon dioxide emissions: an assessment of the uncertainties
Energy Policy
(2005)
- M. van Lieshout et al.
Climate change and malaria: analysis of the SRES climate and socio-economic scenarios
Global Environmental Change
(2004)
- J.P. Weyant
Introduction and Overview
Energy Economics
(2004)
- N.W. Arnell
Climate change and global water resources
Global Environmental Change
(1999)
- C. Azar et al.
Targets for Stabilization of Atmospheric CO2
Science
(1997)
- D.J. Campbell-Lendrum et al.
How much disease could climate change cause?
- CEC (2005a) Winning the Battle against Global Climate Change, Communication from the Commission to the Council, the...
- CEC (2005b) Winning the Battle against Global Climate Change—Background Paper, Commission Staff Working Paper,...
- CEU—Council of the European Union (1996), 1939th Council Meeting, Luxembourg, 25 June...
- CEU—Council of the European Union (2004), 2632nd Council Meeting, Brussels, 20 December...
- S.J. Cohen et al.
Climate change and resource management in the Columbia River Basin
Water International
(2000)
- S. Dessai et al.
Defining and Experiencing Dangerous Climate Change
Climatic Change
(2004)
The European Environment—State and Outlook 2005
(2005)
- European Parliament (2005) Resolution on Winning the Battle Against Climate Change. European Parliament...
- S. Fankhauser et al.
The aggregation of climate change damages: a welfare theoretic approach
Environmental and Resource Economics
(1997)
- K.D. Frederick
Adapting to Climate Impacts on the Supply and Demand for Water
Climatic Change
(1997)
- J.M. Gregory et al.
A model intercomparison of changes in the Atlantic thermohaline circulation in response to increasing atmospheric CO2 concentration
Geophysical Research Letters
(2005)
- W. Hare
Assessment of Knowledge on Impacts of Climate Change—Contribution to the Specification of Art. 2 of the UNFCCC
(2003)
- W. Hare et al.
What is Dangerous Climate Change? Initial Results of a Symposium on Key Vulnerable Regions Climate Change and Article 2 of the UNFCCC
(2004)
- House of Lords. (2005) The Economics of Climate Change, HL Paper 12-I, Select Committee on Economic Affairs 2nd Report...
- B. Hurd et al.
Economic effects of climate change on US water resources
Meeting the Climate Challenge—Recommendations of the International Climate Change Taskforce
(2005)
- P.D. Jones et al.
Global and hemispheric temperature anomalies—land and marine records
- D.C. Keeling et al.
Atmospheric CO2 Records from Sites in the SIO Air Sampling Network
- K. Keller et al.
Avoiding Dangerous Anthropogenic Interference with the Climate System
Climatic Change
(2005)
- Lanchberry, J., 2005. Ecosystem Loss and its Implications for Greenhouse Gas Concentration Stabilisation. International...
- Leemans, R., van Vliet, A., 2005. Responses of Species to Changes in Climate Determine Climate Protection Targets....
- P.M. Link et al.
Possible economic impacts of a shutdown of the thermohaline circulation: an application of FUND
Portuguese Economic Journal
(2004)
- D.C. Major et al.
Water resources planning and climate change assessment methods
Climatic Change
(1997)
Cited by (79)
2017, Engineering
The final declaration made by the L’Aquila G8 Summit expressed willingness to limit the global temperature rise to within 2 °C of pre-industrial levels along with other countries, so that the global greenhouse gas emissions would be reduced by 50% before 2050, and so that developed countries should reduce emissions by 80% or more by 2050. Although the scientific significance of taking a 2 °C temperature rise as the goal was unclear [19], a strong push from the EU at the political level extended the discussion of the global temperature goal from the scientific level to the international political and diplomatic levels. The 35th G8 Summit in July 2009 and the subsequent Major Economies Forum on Energy and Climate (MEF) were held just before the Copenhagen Climate Change Conference, attracting worldwide attention.
2010, Global Environmental Change
The veracity of computer models of climate could be tested against this singular index of globalised climate performance, while the human influence on climate could be discovered through detection and attribution studies which used the trend in global temperature as ‘the smoking gun’ (e.g. Wigley and Raper, 1991). And beyond mere scientific convenience, political and ethical arguments about desirable and undesirable globalised climate states could be gathered around the performance of this one index (see Tol, 2007; Randalls, 2010). But collapsing human knowledge about climate change into one global signature hides far more than it discloses.
View all citing articles on Scopus
David Pearce promised to give comments on an earlier version of this paper, but time did not allow him to do this. David taught me how to apply economic analysis to political issues, and the importance of intellectual honesty above all else. This paper is dedicated to his memory.
Copyright © 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.